8. Freeze Peacetime Spending

A Plan to Renew the Promise of American Life, Plank 8


previous plank summary | contents | intro | next plank


Plank 8. Freeze peacetime spending

Specific Recommendations

8.1. Generate routine, modest federal budget surpluses by means of a comprehensive, enforceable spending freeze.

8.2. Establish a statutory cap on total federal peacetime expenditures, defined initially as a share of gross domestic product, and then, after the restoration of honest, constitutional money, as a specific number of dollars.

8.3. Enforce the statutory expenditure cap by means of automatic sequesters and presidential impoundments of unspent funds.

8.4. Offset spending increases, and tax cuts, with spending cuts of equal or greater value.

8.5. Offset tax hikes with tax cuts of equal or greater value. Only increase overall tax receipts when trading up (for example, when replacing a production tax with a consumption tax) or in a true emergency like a declared war.

8.6. To make federal spending more manageable, convert the form of spending, wherever possible, from permanent to annual (in budget jargon, from ‘mandatory’ to ‘discretionary’ appropriations).

8.7. To reduce unproductive friction in the appropriation process, automatically renew each annual appropriations bill at the end of the fiscal year at, say, 99.9 percent of the previous year’s level.

8.8. Devote surpluses to devolution, debt reduction, and tax relief — never to net spending hikes.


Comments

The previous plank proposed a strong but flexible cap on government debt, as a way to rein in the size and scope of government, and suggested a mechanism to incentivize policymakers to respect such a cap (‘hit your numbers or hit the road’). In this plank, and the three that follow, I’ll try to answer the more mundane question of how we can live under it.

As we’ve seen, the five rules of fiscal common sense are limit spending, tax lightly, borrow the minimum, maintain a surplus, and pay down debt. The first rule is ‘limit spending,’ and it’s first for a reason.

Uncle Sam doesn’t limit spending — and hasn’t, for decades. Are we surprised he’s in debt?

A government with even half a brain spends less than it earns. A prudent government avoids deficits and deliberately seeks small surpluses as a matter of routine. And importantly, it uses those surpluses, not to boost spending, but rather to reduce debt and taxes. Using surpluses to boost spending is a form of madness, the fiscal equivalent of taking the hair of the dog.

The simplest way to limit spending is to freeze it — all of it. Simply impose a cap on total expenditures at their current level and manage spending as necessary under that cap. Whenever an additional dollar is needed in one place, eliminate a dollar of spending somewhere else, or, if necessary, take an additional dollar from the public in taxes.

This is pay-as-you-go, the epitome of common sense. In its ideal form, the spending cap is fixed. It doesn’t move. It doesn’t grow with inflation or population or economic output. It stays put while the natural process of economic growth increases receipts to the point where the lines cross and deficits disappear and surpluses become routine.

Now, to be sure, pay-as-you-go is hard, politically speaking, but in the long run it’s easier than the alternative. The alternative is selective austerity. Politicians and the public bristle at making specific hard choices, because nobody wants to be the sacrificial lamb on the fiscal altar. But people can stomach a policy of general sacrifice. Make the belt-tightening universal, ask everyone to contribute, spare no sacred cow, protect no special interest, and the public will go along. Reluctantly, perhaps. But no one can say, ‘This is unfair, you’re singling me out.’

It helps, of course, to set the cap reasonably high, so the needed course corrections will be small and routine.

It also helps to make the most difficult changes early. Doing so makes a freeze policy comparatively easy to maintain thereafter.

It may even be necessary, at first, to increase spending. That’s right. A temporary rise in spending may be the price we have to pay to secure structural changes that ensure permanent, long-term savings. Get the structure right, and the dollars take care of themselves.

Admittedly — and this is a serious challenge — the discipline of a freeze policy will be difficult in the absence of honest money. So long as Uncle Sam can print money, our beloved Congress-critters will feel little incentive to restrain anything — spending, deficits, or debt. After all, why would a politician risk being thrown out of office for spending cuts or tax hikes, which are nearly always unpopular, when the problem can be papered over with, well, paper?

And honest money will also be hard to achieve without an enforceable debt cap. And ideally, we’d have a state federalism veto, to boot.

Realistically, again, politicians will not be able to maintain the discipline to enforce a true spending freeze without reforms that change their incentives.

So, I will confess, we have a bit of a chicken and egg problem. It’s hard to freeze spending without changing politicians’ incentives, and it’s hard to change their incentives without an enforceable spending freeze.

But this is no reason to despair. Let’s grant, for argument’s sake, that a freeze is impossible without the key structural constraints I just mentioned (honest money, debt cap, and a federalism veto). A freeze is still a good idea in principle. And we will certainly need it, once those structural constraints are in place. So, the prudent course, it seems, is to figure out, well in advance, how we can make the freeze work, should conditions become favorable. And with any luck, doing so will help to make them favorable.

Incidentally, by a ‘freeze,’ I mean a dollar cap: total expenditures remain the same or go down from year to year in actual dollar terms and not just as a percentage of economic output (gross domestic product — a so-called share-of-GDP cap. A GDP-based spending cap is not a true spending freeze. It floats. It lets government spending grow with the economy. Plus, the definition of ‘GDP’ is easily manipulated by politicians and bureaucrats.

Alas, it’s realistic to assume the political class will insist on a ‘share of GDP’ cap. Fiscal conservatives should be willing to live with that, as a transitional step, so long as the definition of GDP is fixed and not-easily-gamed and so long as we keep a true dollar cap in sight as our ultimate goal.

The good news is a compromise along these lines could make a spending freeze policy more politically feasible, even in the absence of other constraints.

Okay, so where should we set our share-of-GDP cap? I would propose three percent of GDP. Yes, three percent. Why? Because that was the peacetime average for the first century and more under the present Constitution — before the progressives went to work. Three percent is historically precedented. It’s doable. It’s clearly not an impediment to national prosperity. /1

Even a fiscally conservative reader may be gasping at this point, What about national security?! A fair question. National security is expensive. It’s true we weren’t a superpower before the mid-twentieth century. Today, we have a coalition of free nations to protect and must maintain a military force of awesome power with an ability to project decisive force across vast distances at speed. But why not ask our allies to shoulder more of the burden? Why not ask them to contribute more to their own defense?

If the reader believes three percent is too low, fine. Make it six. Make it nine. The important thing is to have a target and stick to it. If we never set a target, we’ll never hit it. /2

Progress would of course have to be gradual. The current federal expenditure level, as of this writing, is about 23 percent of GDP. To get it below single digits overnight would be economically disruptive and thus a political nonstarter. So, make it a process. Shrink the federal footprint gradually, bit by bit over time, and make necessary tradeoff choices along the way.

The greatest challenge will be what to do about entitlements, because that’s where the money is. Sixty percent of the budget today goes to entitlements like Social Security, Medicare, Medicaid, and health care tax breaks. Throw in debt service, and we’re at two-thirds of federal spending. This ‘untouchable’ auto-pilot spending is growing faster than receipts. Which means the budget cannot be balanced in any sustainable way absent reforms that constrain it. /3

So long as the ‘untouchable’ two-thirds of spending is growing faster than receipts, we will always be bumping up against the ceiling. Routine surpluses will be structurally impossible.

Aha. We have a structural deficit, so we need structural reforms. Does that put us back at a freeze being politically impossible? No. It just means we have to be creative. /4

Before we identify creative solutions, let’s elimiante a number of suggested solutions that won’t work.

We will not be able to ‘grow’ our way out of the deficit as it is currently structured. In a budget where spending consistently and continuously grows faster than receipts, GDP growth is never going to be rapid enough to close the gap. Yes, we might stumble into balance on a lucky day, as we did in the late ’90s, but it won’t last. We can’t coast our way to easy street.

Nor can we eliminate the deficit by reducing waste, fraud, and abuse, which are difficult to identify and impossible to remove surgically.

Nor can we eliminate the deficit by reducing foreign aid or welfare for illegal immigrants. They’re minuscule.

Nor can we eliminate the deficit by cutting the one-third of spending that is annually appropriated. About half this amount is national defense, which is government’s top job and vital to us all. Cutting it too deeply would be risky. And even if we eliminated every penny of discretionary spending, including defense, the deficit would inevitably return because the growth rate of auto-pilot spending exceeds the growth rate of receipts.

The hard fact is right there in front of us: any serious freeze plan will include the ‘untouchable’ two-thirds of the budget. Entitlements cannot be kept off the table.

As I said earlier, a freeze policy has to be comprehensive — no exceptions, no sacred cows. In wartime, to be sure, we may have no choice but to temporarily suspend the freeze to allow the necessary spike in military expenditures. But in peacetime, defense should not be exempt from ordinary budgetary discipline.

What about the idea of automatic, across-the-board cuts (‘sequesters’)? What if, for example, at the start of every year we just trimmed every program by whatever amount is necessary to restore balance in the coming year? It’s not a bad idea in principle. In fact, it’s a good idea. But the automatic cuts would have to be small to be politically sustainable, or else the politicians would waive, reverse, or swiss-cheese them. And even if we got into the habit of making such trims, we would still not be able to sustain the plan without permanent structural reforms.

Spending must be largely under control before sequestration can be imposed successfully. In other words, it’s a tool for enforcing a freeze but not a great tool for achieving one.

Freeze or no freeze, avoiding a debt crisis requires that we cut some programs more deeply than others, and must eliminate some programs altogether. Uncle Sam must exit whole lines of business. There is no alternative. The math is remorseless.

Which lines of business? Obviously, those that Congress should never have gotten into in the first place, either because they’re unconstitutional or because they don’t work, or they’re a waste of money, or because the states and the private sector can handle them better. For starters, health, education, and welfare. The feds have almost no constitutional authority to spend on those activities. So, that’s where I’d start.

Which brings us to devolution. It is the obvious remedy for many, perhaps most, of our federal fiscal ills. But since I discuss it in detail in the devolution plank, I won’t duplicate the discussion of it here.

Attentive readers will notice that I’ve avoided mention of such popular ideas as ‘zero-based budgeting’ (sunsetting every program annually, and continuing only those that make sense) and the so-called ‘penny plan’ (cutting everything by one percent annually, until balance is achieved). While appealing on paper, these ideas, like a true freeze policy, are probably not going to be sustainable absent serious entitlement reforms, reinforced by sensible procedural reforms (such as sequestration, impoundments, and so on).

So, let’s take the bull by the horns. (Perhaps I should have called this the ‘reform entitlements’ plank.)

Did I mention this policy would be hard? It will. But it’s not impossible, not if we’re serious and patient and take the long view.

Specific Entitlement Reforms

Entitlement reform is step one. Step two, in a time of surplus, is to devolve entitlements to the states. (Step three: don’t create any new ones.)

When an entitlement cannot be devolved for some reason, we should take it off auto-pilot, that is, transform it from permanently to annually appropriated spending. And if necessary, as a first transitional step, we should block-grant it to the states. In most if not all cases, it will help to means-test and/or voucherize it as well.

What’s a block grant? A simple, annual, lump-sum for a particular purpose. Ideally, the grant does not grow with population or inflation but remains flat over time. This ensures the money is spent efficiently. But even a block grant that grows with population or inflation is better than an open-ended entitlement.

Okay, but how should we reform today’s specific entitlements? Here’s how I’d do it.

Social Security. I wouldn’t bother with such conventional but unpopular ‘reforms’ as benefit cuts, tax hikes, age hikes, or — alas! — personal accounts. Instead, we should transform it into a simple, solid, effective anti-poverty program. Focus it on keeping people out of poverty. Means-test the benefits, meaning deny them to those who don’t need them. And, as we’ve seen, I’d also eliminate the payroll tax and fund Social Security from consumption taxes. And oh yes, I think we should amend the Constitution to make the program lawful.

P.S. In principle, money given to individuals by the government is income and, so long as we tax income, we should tax it as such. So, until we abolish income taxation, we should treat Social Security and other cash-transfer benefits as ordinary taxable income (and increase the benefits initially, to hold recipients harmless). As part of this change, we should repeal the existing, special tax on Social Security benefits. On the same principle, all government income transfers should be treated as income for purposes of measuring poverty. Finally, to help keep people out of poverty, we should eliminate required minimum distributions (RMDs) from tax-deferred IRAs. (Personally, I’d convert all tax-deferred IRA options into tax-free, Roth-style accounts — again, in a way that holds people harmless during the transition.)

Medicare. Means-test eligibility for benefits. Ideally, cap and voucherize the benefit to maximize individual choice and control. Eliminate the payroll tax and fund Medicare from other revenue sources. And importantly, make participation in it truly voluntary for individuals. (For all practical purposes, Medicare is a prison. That’s un-American.)

Medicaid. As a first step, either block-grant it or, alternatively, assume it into the federal portfolio, relieving the states of their obligation to help fund it. The latter option may seem counterintuitive, but the current, condominium structure of the program is so diabolically flawed that to get it under somebody’s control — anyone’s — is clearly more important that who controls it. We can’t reform what we can’t control. If we do take the federal assumption path, Congress should cap and voucherize the benefit as well, to maximize individual choice and personal control. And as soon as conditions permit, we should devolve Medicaid to the states, where it belongs.

The Affordable Care Act. Devolve it, both the mandates and the subsidies. If necessary, as a transitional first step, block-grant it. At all events, repeal its individual mandate, which is a true abomination. And as long as this program remains in the federal portfolio, we should cap and voucherize the subsidies to maximize individual choice and control. Now, with such a politically charged scheme, it may be necessary to proceed incrementally, even haltingly. Look for ways to ease the mandates — create holes in the health care Berlin Wall big enough for people to escape through. Eventually, the vast majority of people will escape, and the wall’s continued presence will seem quaint. The ultimate goal, again, should be devolution.

The Tax Exclusion for Employer-Sponsored Insurance. Eliminate the income tax. Until that happens, we should ideally eliminate the biggest loophole, the income-tax exclusion for employer-sponsored health insurance. But since that would be disruptive, and a political nonstarter, we should think in terms of a transition. As a first transitional step we should convert the exclusion into a fixed-amount subsidy, to maximize individual choice and control. And we should allow people to use this subsidy either inside or outside the workplace. Make it available to individuals in lieu of the current, open-ended exclusion (and any other federal health coverage subsidy for which they may be eligible). Let it take the form of an optional, fixed-amount, refundable tax credit that the participant may use for whatever form of health insurance he or she likes. Let people save any unspent funds in a tax-advantaged, Roth-style savings account. Note: To maximize competition and avoid needless complexity, I would not means-test the health credit. But I would make those who voluntarily opt into it permanently ineligible for the existing ACA percent-of-premium credit, which is inherently inflationary.

Other Income Support Programs. This category incudes Disability Insurance, Unemployment Insurance, Food Stamps, Nutrition Assistance, and similar programs. Devolve them all. As a first step, reform them, and then block grant them. As a general rule, we should employ means-testing, time limits, work requirements, anti-double-dipping rules, anti-fraud protections, and lock-out periods for non-compliance with program rules. And also, where necessary, wait lists.

Note: Federal civilian and military pensions and health benefits should not be devolved because they are earned benefits of federal employment.


Notes

1/ When I refer to the ‘peacetime’ average of federal spending, I mean when no formal congressional declaration of war is in effect. As for the term ‘declaration of war,’ it must of course include so-called ‘authorizations of military force’ (AUMFs), which are just declarations of war pretending to be something else.

2/ Surely, any figure north of single digits needs to be justified by something more persuasive than ‘It’s traditional, these days.’ One man’s tradition is another man’s historical anomaly. And viewed from the standpoint of American history, our current, high level of government spending is indeed anomalous.

3/ One-third of federal spending is appropriated on an annual basis, meaning it expires at the end of each fiscal year if Congress takes no action. This is usually referred to as ‘discretionary’ spending. Temporary, and usually annual appropriation, used to be the norm, and should be again. The idea of permanent appropriations was anathema because it imposes burdens on future generations without their consent. Appropriations should be short-lived. Sunset clauses are as beautiful as sunsets. But wait. Why do I endorse a form of auto-pilot in the context annually appropriated spending (continuing existing spending at, say, 99.9 percent of the current level, in the absence of a new appropriation)? Is that not a self-contradiction. It’s not, because spending ‘cliffs’ favor spending hikes. Automatic continuation at a slightly reduced level shifts leverage to those who seek to hold the line on spending. The continuation model is admittedly suboptimal, compared to universal, annual sunsets, but it’s more fiscally prudent.

4/ By the way, about half of entitlement spending goes to retirement programs and health care, and most of that goes to old people. So it’s technically true that Uncle Sam is ‘a pension plan with an army.’

Constitutional Amendments

This plank does not propose any constitutional amendments, but realistically, it will not be sustainable without the help of the amendments proposed in the debt-limitation, honest money, and independent agencies planks.


Benefits

Permanently reduces the size and burden of the federal establishment.

Gives Congress stronger incentives to eliminate unnecessary and unconstitutional programs and agencies.


Revised: March 4, 2018.

First published: June 21, 2013.

Author: Dean Clancy.

previous plank summary | contents | intro | next plank

Leave a Reply

Your email address will not be published. Required fields are marked *