6. Restore Sound Money

A Plan to Renew the Promise of American Life, Plank 6

Plank 5     Contents     Plank 7

Plank 6. Restore sound money.


Specific Recommendations

6.1. Restore constitutional money and thereby return control over the money supply to the American people, and thus ensure economic health and fiscal discipline, by returning the United States to its constitutionally mandated bimetallic system, based on the (silver) dollar as defined in the Constitution and reflected in the Coinage Act of 1792.

6.2. Scrupulously adhere to the Constitution’s five monetary rules: 1) The basic unit is the dollar, a silver coin containing 371.25 grains of pure silver. 2) Only gold or silver coins, or currency backed by the same, are legal tender. 3) No state may issue coins or currency. 4) No one may counterfeit U.S. coins or currency. 5) Fiat money is forbidden.

6.3. Overturn, by statutory and judicial means, the mischievous doctrines of the Legal Tender and Gold Clause Cases, which erroneously confer on the U.S. Government  “plenary” economic powers said to be “inherent” in national sovereignty, but which are in fact antithetical both to the constitutional text and to the spirit of free republican government.

6.4. Revise the federal legal-tender statute (31 U.S.C. 5103) to declare: 1) that gold and silver coins and currency, regardless of issuer or denomination, are sufficient for the payment of private debts, and 2) that United States gold and silver coins and currency are sufficient for the payment of public charges, taxes, and dues. Define the term “currency,” for these purposes, as notes readily redeemable in and fully backed by gold or silver coins (specie).

6.5. Revise the so-called gold-clause statute (31 U.S.C. 5118) to restore the enforceability of valid private contracts that require payment in a specific medium, even if that medium is not legal tender.

6.6. Abolish all taxes and penalties on gold and silver coins and 100-percent specie-backed notes, regardless of issuer or denomination, and all taxes on gold and silver bullion.

6.7. Allow any bank, not just a privileged central bank, to issue 100-percent specie-backed notes that may lawfully circulate as currency.

6.8. Supply the public with United States gold and silver coins at the Mint on demand, in exchange for bullion or currency.

6.9. Reestablish dollar-gold convertibility at a stable, nondeflationary price.

6.10. Gently remove from circulation all fiat-money notes issued by or under the authority of the United States government.

6.11. Reestablish a sound, honest coinage. Specifically: 1) mark all United States gold and silver coins to show the coin’s actual precious-metal content, both in terms of weight in troy ounces and purity in parts per thousand, 2) denominate all United States coins and currency in terms of the dollar as that term is used in the federal Constitution and the Coinage Act of 1792, meaning a silver coin containing 371.25 grains of pure or 416 grains of standard silver, 3) except for the copper penny, replace all United States base-metal coins with silver coins, and reinstitute the issuance of gold coins, as set forth in the 1792 Coinage Act, 4) never vary the silver content of the United States dollar and its related fractional coins, since the (silver) dollar is the basic unit of our economic system and its definition can only be changed by constitutional amendment, and 5) from time to time, and only when necessary to ensure the continuous circulation of both gold and silver coins, amend the Coinage Act to adjust the official exchange rate between gold and silver coins or to alter the precious-metal content of gold coins.


Explanation

The purpose of this plank is to protect our liberty and promote our prosperity by protecting our property—to end the government’s ability to meddle with the value of our money. That would be the greatest of blessings.

The plank does this by following the Constitution. Read in conjunction with the Ninth and Tenth Amendments, the Constitution’s seven money clauses establish the following five monetary rules for the United States:

  1. The basic unit is the dollar, a silver coin containing 371.25 grains of pure silver.
  2. Only gold or silver coins, or currency backed by the same, are legal tender.
  3. No state may issue coins or currency.
  4. No one may counterfeit U.S. coins or currency.
  5. Fiat money is forbidden.

The term “dollar” in the Constitution refers to a specific silver coin of a fixed weight and fineness, namely, the Spanish milled dollar, which on average contained 371.25 grains of pure or 416 grains of standard silver. That coin, a specific measure of silver, is the basic unit of the U.S. economic system. As we shall see, to alter the definition of “dollar” would require a constitutional amendment.

The term “currency,” as I use it here, means banknotes that are freely redeemable in and fully backed by gold or silver coins.

“Legal tender” is whatever the government requires creditors to accept in payment of debts, public or private or both. Under the Constitution, gold and silver coins are the only things that may be required to be used as legal tender.

Note: While it is not necessary to have a legal tender statute, most countries do so, as a convenience to debtors and tax collectors. Typically governments declare their own official coins and currency to be legal tender, for both private and public debts (i.e., taxes). Many governments also establish a monopoly central bank to issue legal tender notes, though this too is not necessary.

The term “fiat money,” as I use it here, means banknotes or paper money with legal-tender status but which are not backed by anything of value.

The term “bills of credit,” as used in the Constitution, means the same thing as “fiat money,” that is, worthless paper. To be clear, the Constitution does not forbid paper money. It does forbid worthless paper money. The states are explicitly forbidden to “emit bills of credit,” and implicitly, under the principle of enumerated powers, so is Congress.

Thanks to the five rules, the Constitution puts the country on what amounts to a bimetallic, silver-and-gold standard measured in terms of dollars.

This system is both simple and ingenious. It requires no centralized control of the money supply, no central bank, no central planners to manipulate the price of money (interest rates). Rather, it leaves money under the control of the people acting freely in the marketplace. 

That is our policy. It is a wise and just policy—and, I would argue, the only policy consistent with economic prosperity and political freedom.

Why Sound Money?

Sound money, meaning money that holds its value over time, is an essential prerequisite for stable prices, a smoother business cycle, and real economic health.

Sound money promotes fiscal discipline, balanced budgets, and low taxes. Sound money is necessary for free trade. Sound money helps the poor escape poverty. Sound money helps ensure a large and stable middle class.

The blessings of sound money are not just economic but also political. It safeguards our freedom. In the words of Austrian School economist Ludwig von Mises:

It is impossible to grasp the meaning of the idea of sound money if one does not realize that it was devised as an instrument for the protection of civil liberties against despotic inroads on the part of governments. Ideologically it belongs in the same class with political constitutions and bills of rights.

Sound money is the best friend of the workingman, the saver, the taxpayer, the family breadwinner—in short, all of us.

Why Not Unsound Money?

Unsound money, meaning money that does not hold its value over time, is the primary cause of inflation and a major contributing factor to economic bubbles and financial panics (deflation). Unsound money cheats savers of their wealth and causes unemployment. It hurts the poor.

Unsound money is the enemy of the worker, the saver, the retiree, the breadwinner, the taxpayer. Unsound money weakens social trust, burdens old age, and takes food from the family table.

Unsound money is a tax on the poor. Restoring sound money amounts to giving the poor a pay raise. Incidentally, restoring sound money means never having to raise the compulsory minimum wage or give cost-of-living adjustments.

What Is Money?

Money is traditionally defined as whatever thing most people in a given place have agreed to use as a medium of exchange and which also serves as a handy unit of account and a reliable store of value. Money arises naturally, out of private transactions. Just about any commodity can be enlisted to serve as money, but gold and silver have traditionally been the favorites, because, compared to most other candidates, they have in the greatest measure the most desirable qualities of money: they’re durable, portable, malleable, divisible, easily recognizable, and naturally limited in quantity. They may go out of fashion in some places and times, but they never really go away. Their popularity is perpetual. That’s because in good times and bad they tend to hold their value relative to all other goods. Gold and silver are not terribly good investments, but they are great hedges against both inflation and deflation. They can weather anything. Basically, they’re Mother Nature’s answer to the question, “What is money?”

Why should money be “sound”? Because money is an economy’s lifeblood, part of every transaction. When the currency loses some of its value, everyone who relies on it becomes poorer. When money sneezes, the economy catches cold.

Governments love to cheapen the currency, to cheat their creditors and raise taxes without a vote. But no good purpose is served by government control of money. There is no need for a central authority to “manage” the money supply. There is no need to centrally dictate what shall serve as the common currency, no need to tell private individuals what they may and may not use as a medium of exchange in private transactions. Government’s only role, really, is to say what currency or currencies shall be used in payment of taxes. Wise governments require only silver and gold, or notes backed by the same, to be used for this purpose.

A free society needs both separation of church and state and separation of money and state. No state church. No central bank. (About the latter, more anon.)

Three Kinds of Money

The three main kinds of money are: 1) commodity money (e.g., gold and silver coins); 2) representative or fiduciary money (e.g., bank notes that are redeemable for commodity money); and 3) fiat money (e.g., bank notes not redeemable for anything of value). My nicknames for these are: sound money, trust-me money, and funny money. Only a system based on sound money is truly sound.

Five Bad Things

Governments seem to meddle with real money in five main ways: 1) They produce fiat money, which has no connection to anything of value. 2) They require fiat money be used as legal tender in all transactions, public and private, in order to confiscate wealth without formally levying taxes. 3) They debase or cheapen the currency by declaring it to have a value greater than it really does. 4) They tax rival currencies, to drive sound money out of circulation (because it competes with their fiat money). And 5) they authorize a central bank to exercise monopoly control over the banking system so they can print fiat money out of thin air.

What is the path to sound money? Eschew these five bad things. How many of the five bad things do we do nowadays? You guessed it. All of them.

Metallic Standard or Central Bank?

What’s a “gold standard”? (I will refer to it here as a metallic standard.) It’s basically a policy that requires the government to exchange pieces of paper for pieces of metal and vice versa. That’s it. A metallic standard shifts control of money from the government to the people. There is nothing dangerous or difficult about following a metallic standard, unless your goal is to do one of the five bad things. None of the arguments against a metallic standard is persuasive, in my opinion. (For a succinct refutation of them, see James G. Rickards’s book, The New Case for Gold.)

People who dismiss reliance on a precious metal like gold as a “barbarous relic” are, whether they realize it or not, advocating for deficits, inflation, and the confiscation and redistribution of wealth via monetary policy. Countries that switch from a metallic standard to exclusive reliance on fiat money do so precisely to achieve deficits, inflation, and the confiscation and redistribution of wealth. They want to spend and borrow beyond their means, and a precious metal stands in their way.

A metallic standard produces price-stability and superior employment outcomes for everyone because it imposes a limit on the total money supply. The government can’t easily expand the amount of money, which is another way of saying it can’t inflate prices, including the price of money itself, which is the interest rate. The market sets these things, and the result is superior efficiency and better outcomes, i.e., more goods for everyone.

Under a metallic standard, significant inflation is rare, and hyperinflation is essentially impossible because the money supply can only grow at the rate that the supply of the precious metal increases. It is possible, of course, for a government to follow a metallic standard and also issue fiat money. But the market will always have more confidence in sound money than unsound. So precious metals are an effective constraint on government, provided the government doesn’t impede people’s free access to, and use of, those metals.

As I noted at the outset, the U.S. Constitution puts the United States on a bimetallic standard of silver and gold, with silver serving as the base. It does not impose a gold standard, per se, nor a silver standard. Rather, it imposes a bimetallic, silver-and-gold standard controlled by the people rather than by politicians and bureaucrats.

As I see it, there are only three ways for a government to “manage” a currency: a) a metallic standard, b) a central bank that mimics a metallic standard, or c) a central bank that prints money. The United States currently employs the last option, a central bank that prints money. We would be better off with the second option, a central bank that mimicked a metallic standard. But we would be still better off with the first option: a metallic standard, pure and simple. Happily, the Constitution requires that very thing.

So the remedy is pretty obvious. Since our central bank, the Federal Reserve System, prints money, we should replace it with the constitutional bimetallic standard. I am wiling to indulge the proposition that we might, as a transitional step, constrain the Fed to mimic a metallic standard. But that approach would have to be clearly transitional and kept brief. The Fed itself might be kept around, but it could not be permitted to deviate from the Constitution’s requirements.

The alleged purpose of the Fed when it was created in 1913 was to help prevent the economy from freezing up during a national credit shortage. The Fed would serve as a clearinghouse that could shift credit from one local region of the country to another and act as a lender of last resort, meaning a bailout mechanism should a credit crunch threaten the whole system. Being the lender of last resort means being the guy who can drum up needed cash and assets and keep the system liquid, when everyone else is fresh out.

Needing a lender of last resort is perhaps inevitable. But the lender of last resort does not have to be the federal taxpayer. It could be private banks or extremely wealthy individuals. The Federal Reserve Act shifted the job from the private sector to the American taxpayer.

When the Fed was created in 1913, the United States was on what amounted to a monometallic gold standard. In subsequent decades, the Fed evolved into a central bank that prints fiat money with no connection to real money. Today the Fed nominally pursues two main goals, laid down for it by Congress, namely, to ensure stable prices and to ensure full employment. In reality, its true goals are first, to benefit its member banks and the banking industry generally, and second, to benefit its masters in Congress by, in effect, monetizing their debts. Government living within its means is deemed unthinkable by the political class, and the Fed’s one true job, at the end of the day, is to debase the currency. In doing so, it has to navigate between two shoals: it must keep the politicians happy but not make the people restive. Congress needs inflation to cheat its creditors. Inflation makes voters cranky.

This is a big reason why the political class instinctively insists on shielding the Fed from criticism or accountability. It tells us the Fed is independent of politics, and that this “independence” is essential. But it’s all a myth. The Fed follows the election returns. In practice it tends to bend to the will of the incumbent president, because of his ability to appoint Fed governors and his other fiscal powers, as well as his bully pulpit. An old saying has it that “The president gets the dollar he wants.” If he wants a weak dollar, the Fed accommodates him. If he wants a strong dollar, the Fed accommodates him. The trouble with this fact is there is no constitutional authority for the president to dictate the value of the dollar.

When the Fed was still working within a metallic standard, between 1913 and 1933, there was no inflation. At that time, the budget was balanced. Congress didn’t need inflation. Between 1933 and 1971, the Fed operated within a partial gold standard. Inflation was low, and so were deficits. Since 1968, when Uncle Sam cut the last ties to silver, and 1971, when it cut the last ties to gold, inflation has been chronic, which has been great for the politicians and bankers and bad for the rest of us. The Fed tries to produce enough inflation to please the spenders but not so much that it triggers a public backlash. By and large, it has done this more or less well, although in recent years it has found its old toolkit—money-printing, quantitative easing, forward guidance, etc.—ineffectual. It is currently engaged in a desperate experiment to force interest rates (the price of money) to zero, in the hopes that people will spend rather than save, thereby reviving a lackluster economy. If that fails, it will have no option left but to resort to negative interest rates (which is basically banks charging us for the privilege of depositing our money with them). Should that too fail, there will be one last resort, perhaps, the same one the government used in 1933: devalue the dollar. “Devaluation” is a fancy word for reducing people’s incomes by reducing their wealth forcibly, which is what a tax does. Devaluation is a tax.

To reinflate the economy, the Fed will as its very last resort restore dollar-gold convertibility, though not at the old, pre-1971 price ($35 an ounce). This time, to avoid being deflationary—that is, to avoid tanking the economy—it will have to be at a much higher price, say, $10,000 an ounce.

Free financial tip: Buy yourself a small stash of physical gold and keep it where the government can’t seize it. If gold is remonetized, as seems inevitable, you’ll be enriched, or at least not as deeply impoverished, compared to other people, thanks to your hoard.

I said the Fed has done its job more or less well. But on the other side of the coin, I think it is not going too far to say that misguided Fed monetary policy decisions—abetted by bad fiscal and regulatory policies—caused the crashes of 1929 and 2008 and prolonged the Great Depression and the Great Recession.

I said the Fed achieves its real purpose more or less well, but the Fed is also incompetent, and its incompetence is, occasionally, destructive.

We will always be better off with a metallic standard and market-determined interest rates. The Founders understood this. And they made that understanding the law of the land.

Yes, End the Fed

The modern movements to “end the Fed” and “go back to the gold standard” are essentially the same movement. Each logically entails the other. Sound money is impossible without a metallic standard or something very like it.

Yes, we need to end the Fed as we know it.

We can keep the building and employees, if we wish, though I don’t really see a need to. We can return the Fed to its mission circa 1913, which was to serve as a credit clearinghouse and lender of last resort, operating within a metallic standard. But curb its powers. Don’t let it set interest rates or monetize Congress’s debts.

We should also end its pretense of independence. Make it part of the executive branch, answerable to the Secretary of the Treasury. After Andrew Jackson succeeded in killing the Second Bank of the United States in 1836, this country had no national bank for 77 years, without the world coming to an end. The Treasury took care of “managing” the currency, which isn’t much of a job under a metallic standard.

How Constitutional Money Was Overthrown

The Supreme Court, in its famous Legal Tender Cases and Gold Clause Cases, ruled that Congress has “plenary power” to issue fiat money and dictate its value, pursuant to its power to “regulate the value” of foreign and domestic coin. That’s erroneous. The power to regulate the value of gold and silver coins is limited to the purpose of ensuring that both kinds remain in circulation (i.e., to counteract Gresham’s Law). In these cases, the Court makes the incorrect assumption that the federal government is endowed with attributes of “national sovereignty” like those found in European governments. That assumption has no grounding in the constitutional text and turns the American Revolution on its head. The whole point of the Revolution, and its greatest achievement, was to deny the existence of “sovereignty” in the “rulers” and recognize it in the people, considered as individuals. “All men are created equal”—even you, King George! From which it follows that government must be by the consent of all the people. That consent is reflected in our Constitution, a voluntary yet binding act of “We the People.” The Constitution places limits on the powers of our “rulers.” Congress’s monetary powers, too, are limited. They are by no means “plenary.”

As a constitutional matter, representative paper money may serve as legal tender, but it must represent commodity money, specifically gold and silver coins, and it must be freely redeemable in such coins and fully backed by them. To qualify as legal tender in the U.S., a note must represent the full amount of ready coin held in reserve by the issuer. Fractional-reserve notes don’t count.

How to Restore Constitutional Money

To serve its liberty-protecting function, a national currency needs to have a fixed, stable value.

The Founders understood this and gave the dollar a fixed, stable value by placing the term “dollar” in the Constitution, even though there was no such thing as a United States dollar at the time the Constitution and the Bill of Rights were framed and ratified. That’s right. There was no U.S. dollar.

The term “dollar” in the Constitution refers not to a U.S. coin, but to a Spanish one, the Spanish milled dollar, which circulated widely in the American colonies in the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries. The constitutional definition of “dollar” is thus fixed—a fact that has, alas! been suppressed by the opponents of sound money and forgotten by nearly everyone.

The first U.S. dollars were produced pursuant to the Coinage Act of 1792, which created a United States Mint to coins U.S. dollars, according to the following definition:

DOLLARS OR UNITS–each to be of the value of a Spanish milled dollar as the same is now current, and to contain three hundred and seventy-one grains and four sixteenth parts of a grain of pure, or four hundred and sixteen grains of standard silver.

In terms of weight, that’s about 24 grams of pure silver or 27 grams of standard silver. A dollar is a unit of measure, nothing more. And since it is part of the constitutional text, it can only be changed by constitutional amendment. The Federal Reserve Note in your pocket is only a “dollar” in an analogous and inertial sense—it’s a term we use out of habit. It’s not a dollar in the constitutional sense.*

In the old days, when the Treasury issued U.S. gold and silver certificates freely redeemable in and fully backed by gold and silver, we had constitutional paper money. Those pieces of paper were dollars in the true sense. Today’s Federal Reserve Notes are—well, I don’t know what they are. Sometimes I call them “greenbacks,” to distinguish them from dollars. They have nothing of value standing behind them except a promise to pay in cheap base-metal coins.

But wait. Doesn’t Congress have the “power to regulate the value” of “coined” money? Yes, it does. So doesn’t that mean Congress can redefine the dollar any way it likes, at any time? No!

What the “power to regulate the value thereof” means is Congress can adjust the value of gold coins in relation to silver coins, from time to time, in order to keep both in circulation (i.e., to counteract Gresham’s Law). It does not confer on Congress a power to arbitrarily redefine the value of the dollar any way it pleases.

So what should we do? Enact the specific recommendations of this plank, pronto. The result will be the return of sound money, and with it, an exponential increase in freedom and prosperity and their attendant blessings.


NOTES

* One of the Constitution’s references to the “dollar” is in the Seventh Amendment, which declares: “In Suits at common law, where the value in controversy shall exceed twenty dollars, the right of trial by jury shall be preserved.” Modern courts, amazingly, profess not to know what the Seventh Amendment’s twenty-dollar rule means in practice, because, they claim, the dollar’s value has “changed” since the eighteenth century. But the dollar’s value has not changed. It is still a fixed amount of silver, nothing more. What has changed is our understanding of the word “dollar.” We’ve become confused, because we’ve forgotten the original definition. Once we recover it, it becomes very easy to apply the twenty-dollar rule today. All a judge has to do is take the current troy-ounce-price of silver in terms of Federal Reserve Notes and multiply it by 77.344 percent and multiply the result by twenty. If the result is less than the amount in controversy, the plaintiff is entitled to jury trial, and if it’s more, then he’s not. For a more detailed explanation, see my post on the Constitution’s seven money clauses.

** Here is the text of the current legal tender statute (31 U.S.C. 5103):

United States coins and currency (including Federal reserve notes and circulating notes of Federal reserve banks and national banks) are legal tender for all debts, public charges, taxes, and dues. Foreign gold or silver coins are not legal tender for debts.

This language is both unnecessary and contrary to the Constitution. It should either be repealed or (even better) amended to reflect the Constitution’s original meaning. For example:

United States gold and silver coins and currency are legal tender for all public charges, taxes, and dues.

Gold and silver coins and currency, regardless of issuer or denomination, are legal tender for all private debts.


Constitutional Amendments

This plank requires no constitutional amendments.


Benefits

Will greatly increase personal financial security and incentives to work, save, and invest.

Will end government-created inflation and produce a smoother business cycle, with fewer economic panics and shallower contractions.

Will provide a powerful check on the growth of government.


Summary

Plank 5     Contents     Plank 7

Revised: April 18, 2016.

Published: June 21, 2013.

Author: Dean Clancy.

Add a Comment